Invezz is an independent platform with the goal of helping users achieve financial freedom. In order to fund our work, we partner with advertisers who may pay to be displayed in certain positions on certain pages, or may compensate us for referring users to their services. While our reviews and assessments of each product are independent and unbiased, the order in which brands are presented and the placement of offers may be impacted and some of the links on this page may be affiliate links from which we earn a commission. The order in which products and services appear on Invezz does not represent an endorsement from us, and please be aware that there may be other platforms available to you than the products and services that appear on our website. Read more about how we make money >
Stolper-Samuelson theorem
3 key takeaways
Copy link to section- The Stolper-Samuelson theorem links trade policy changes to shifts in income distribution between labor and capital.
- It predicts that trade liberalization benefits the owners of a country’s abundant factor while harming the owners of the scarce factor.
- The theorem helps explain the impact of globalization and trade on wage inequality and capital returns.
What is the Stolper-Samuelson theorem?
Copy link to sectionThe Stolper-Samuelson theorem is a fundamental result in international trade theory, formulated by economists Wolfgang Stolper and Paul Samuelson in 1941. The theorem is derived from the Heckscher-Ohlin model of trade, which posits that countries export goods that intensively use their abundant factors of production and import goods that intensively use their scarce factors. The Stolper-Samuelson theorem specifically addresses how changes in trade policies, such as tariffs and trade liberalization, influence the distribution of income between different factors of production, typically labor and capital.
Key predictions of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem
Copy link to sectionThe Stolper-Samuelson theorem makes several important predictions about the impact of trade policies on income distribution:
- Trade liberalization: When a country opens up to international trade, the theorem predicts that the real income of the owners of the country’s abundant factor will increase, while the real income of the owners of the scarce factor will decrease. For example, in a labor-abundant country, trade liberalization will benefit workers (the abundant factor) and harm capital owners (the scarce factor).
- Tariff implementation: Conversely, if a country imposes tariffs or trade barriers, the real income of the owners of the scarce factor will increase, while the real income of the owners of the abundant factor will decrease. This is because tariffs protect the industries that use the scarce factor intensively.
- Wage inequality: In developed countries where capital is abundant and labor is relatively scarce, trade liberalization can lead to increased wage inequality, as the returns to capital increase while wages stagnate or decline.
Implications for trade policy and income distribution
Copy link to sectionThe Stolper-Samuelson theorem has significant implications for understanding the effects of globalization and trade policies on income distribution within countries:
- Policy decisions: Policymakers must consider the potential distributive effects of trade policies. Trade liberalization can lead to increased income inequality, requiring complementary policies to support adversely affected groups.
- Globalization: The theorem helps explain the economic tensions that arise from globalization, as different groups within a country experience varying benefits and costs from increased trade.
- Labor markets: The impact on wages and employment can be profound, with potential shifts in demand for different types of labor. For example, trade liberalization may increase demand for skilled labor in capital-abundant countries, exacerbating wage disparities between skilled and unskilled workers.
Examples of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem in action
Copy link to sectionThe Stolper-Samuelson theorem can be observed in various historical and contemporary contexts:
- NAFTA: The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) led to significant changes in income distribution in member countries. In the United States, capital and skilled labor benefited from increased trade, while unskilled labor faced wage pressure.
- China’s WTO accession: China’s entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001 had profound effects on global trade patterns. In China, trade liberalization benefited the abundant labor force, leading to rapid wage growth, while in some developed countries, manufacturing workers faced job losses and wage stagnation.
Criticisms and limitations
Copy link to sectionWhile the Stolper-Samuelson theorem provides valuable insights, it also has limitations and has faced criticisms:
- Simplified assumptions: The model assumes only two factors of production and may not fully capture the complexities of modern economies with multiple factors, industries, and sectors.
- Short-term vs. long-term effects: The theorem primarily addresses long-term equilibrium effects and may not account for short-term adjustment costs and transitional dynamics.
- Factor mobility: The assumption of factor immobility may not hold in reality, as labor and capital can move across borders in response to trade policy changes.
The Stolper-Samuelson theorem offers a crucial framework for understanding how trade policies impact income distribution within a country. By highlighting the differential effects on labor and capital, the theorem provides insights into the economic and social consequences of trade liberalization and protectionism, informing both policymakers and economists about the potential benefits and challenges of global trade.
More definitions
Sources & references

Arti
AI Financial Assistant